Comprehensive Crop Insurance Scheme
(CCIS) has been in operation in the country since Kharif 1985 as an instrument
of risk management in agriculture and as a measure of providing relief to
farmers whose crops are damaged due to natural calamities. The sum insured is
equal to crop loan disbursed subject to a maximum of Rs. 10,000 per farmer. The
premium is charged at the rate of 2 per cent for rice, wheat and millets and 1
per cent for pulses and oilseeds. Since inception of the Scheme in 1985, about
6.45 crore farmers have been covered up to rabi 1997-98 season. The total
amount of claims paid was Rs. 1623 crore as against a premium collection of
about Rs. 313 crore up to rabi, 1997- 98 season. The Scheme is thus unviable.
The losses incurred are met by the Government of India and the concerned state
Governments in the ratio 2:1. The main drawback of the scheme is seen in the
claims entertained for one single crop, namely, groundnut, because of which
Gujarat state alone received Rs. 792 crores as claims compensation out of all India
claims of Rs. 1623 crores. Thus one single crop (groundnut) in just one state (Gujarat ) alone claimed 48.8 percent of total claims
between 1985 to rabi 1997-98.
An Experimental Crop Insurance Scheme
was introduced by the Government of India during rabi 1997-98 season covering
non-loanee small and marginal farmers growing specified crops in selected
districts. The scheme could be implemented only in 14 districts of 5 States. The
premium was totally subsidised. Premium and claims both, were shared by Central
and State Governments in the ratio of 4:1. About 4.78 lakh farmers were covered
for a sum insured of Rs. 172 crore under the scheme during the rabi 1997-98
season. The total premium collected was Rs. 2.86 crore and against that, the
claims amounted to around Rs.
39.78 crore. The Scheme has since been
discontinued from kharif 1998 season. However, an expanded crop insurance
scheme that will cover all farmers and more crops is under active consideration
of the Government.
Economists have proven that farmers stand
to benefit from crop insurance, even unsubsidized crop insurance. However,
private markets for crop insurance worldwide are not highly developed, except
for in a few cases. Skees (2000) documents several reasons for the
underdevelopment of private crop insurance. Subsidized crop insurance crowds
out private insurers and stifles innovation. Farmers are considered to know
their risks better than the government or the private sector, so knowledge of
agriculture is essential for insurers. The need for information increases the
cost of insurance. Agricultural risk is unique—natural disasters can be
widespread and are neither completely independent nor correlated. Studies have
indicated that farmers/decision makers tend to underestimate the risk of damage
by natural causes.
In the United States crop insurance is
subsidized by the government but
administered through private companies.
Hail insurance is not subsidized, so most insurers offer hail insurance along
with the subsidized government policies. Rates are based upon the history of
crop losses due to hail in the county and competition also plays a factor in
keeping rates low. Adverse selection is not an issue because companies set
rates higher for high-risk areas. Moral hazard is also less of a problem, as
hail is a natural event. The multiple-peril insurance subsidized by the government
is considered to be too expensive if offered without subsidies. A crop insurance
agent from Midwest estimated that over half of
the farmers who purchase subsidized multi-peril crop insurance also purchase
hail insurance. The model used for hail insurance can also be used for other
natural disasters, like drought, flood, and wind. The current subsidized insurance
program administered
through private companies is relatively
new. This program is considered to be a significant improvement over the
previous unpopular programs administered by the government, although it is not
flawless. An option for the Indian government is to administer its crop
insurance program through private companies and gradually phase out the
subsidy. This option could best be used for a “transition” period. Initially
subsidizing premium rates for crop insurance offered through private companies
would give the private sector incentive to enter the agricultural sector and
time to gain experience before the withdrawal of subsidies. Crop insurance in South Africa
was started in 1929 when a group of farmers started a pool scheme. Subsidized multi-peril
insurance was offered for some time, but for the past fifteen years no
subsidies have been given. Hail is the main peril covered and many other perils
are also covered. Historical data and past claims play a role in determining
the premiums and damage assessment is the biggest challenge for crop insurers.
Crops at different stages are affected differently by hail, making knowledge
essential for insurers. There are several players and new ones are
continuously targeting this market.
Several crops are covered, including maize, wheat, sunflowers, and citrus
fruits. The South Africa
case illustrates how private individuals can offer crop insurance that is
beneficial to farmers and how crop insurance can still exist after subsidies
are withdrawn. In Canada
crop insurance was administered through an area approach, similar to that of India .
Research from 1995 by Turvey and Islam indicated that the area approach was not
only inequitable but also inefficient. The empirical research from 537 farms
confirmed the belief that individual crop insurance is better in terms of
risk reduction, but premiums would also be
higher. The area approach in Canada
was concluded to be inequitable, as benefits were not fairly distributed. The
most benefits to be accrued would be by the farmers with yields closest to the
average.
The crop insurance in Canada was
voluntary at this time, unlike the NAIS. Adverse selection would be less of a
problem at the individual level when insurance is mandatory.
Cross-subsidization would be more of a problem, because the better farmers
having to purchase insurance would indirectly subsidize the worse farmers. A
1997 study by Sakurai and Reardon indicated that there was an unmet demand for
formal drought insurance in Burkina
Faso . Burkina Faso is a part of the West
African Semi-Arid Tropics (WASAT) and experiences frequent drought. Much of the
farmland in India
is in the semi-arid tropics. The demand for drought insurance was found to
decrease in households with higher overall incomes or more self-insurance. The
authors suggest that crop insurance alone is not sufficient; that policy and
programs that supports self-insurance, such as micro credit or increase of
off-farm employment, are also important. Perhaps in India public funds and government policy
would be better aimed at strengthening self insurance mechanisms, while leaving
crop insurance to the private sector.
No comments:
Post a Comment